Thinking about equilibrium and disequilibrium
On my flight back home last night, I started to try and understand David Glasner's post about sticky prices in terms of information equilibrium. Here's a long quote
All the theory of general equilibrium tells us is that if all trading takes place at the equilibrium set of prices, the economy will be in equilibrium as long as the underlying “fundamentals” of the economy do not change. But in a decentralized economy, no one knows what the equilibrium prices are, and the equilibrium price in each market depends in principle on what the equilibrium prices are in every other market. So unless the price in every market is an equilibrium price, none of the markets is necessarily in equilibrium.
Now it may well be that if all prices are close to equilibrium, the small changes will keep moving the economy closer and closer to equilibrium, so that the adjustment process will converge. But that is just conjecture, there is no proof showing the conditions under which a simple rule that says raise the price in any market with an excess demand and decrease the price in any market with an excess supply will in fact lead to the convergence of the whole system to equilibrium. Even in a Walrasian tatonnement system, in which no trading at disequilibrium prices is allowed, there is no proof that the adjustment process will eventually lead to the discovery of the equilibrium price vector. If trading at disequilibrium prices is allowed, tatonnement is hopeless.
So the real problem is not that prices are sticky but that trading takes place at disequilibrium prices and there is no mechanism by which to discover what the equilibrium prices are. Modern macroeconomics solves this problem, in its characteristic fashion, by assuming it away ...
Let me try and describe this in terms of information transfer (definitions for various terms at link). Let's start with a simplistic information equilibrium relationship between A and B that we will promote to an ensemble of markets with common factor of production B and different information transfer indices k.

The A growth states k are directly related to price (P) growth (change) states with k - 1. These distributions represent an ensemble of markets (see here for a summary of this idea). In general, no individual market (individual squares in a histogram) is required to be in information equilibrium (we can have non-ideal information transfer), so the price may fall anywhere below the ideal (information equilibrium) price. As I said, each box in the histogram is an individual market (as the number of markets approach infinity, the histogram approaches the distribution). Each market can be represented by a supply and demand diagram (partial equilibrium) with either an equilibrium price (at the intersection of the supply and demand curves) or a disequilibrium price (non-ideal information transfer) that falls below the curves.

Probably a better picture is this that shows the histogram better with hundreds of markets:

Let's simplify a bit and talk about only 4 markets, with 3 trading at disequilibrium prices. I drew the partial equilibrium view inside each box in the histogram (each box is a market, and the macroeconomy is a distribution of boxes):

We can see that partial equilibrium analysis can fail in the markets trading at disequilibrium prices:

Additionally, there may be correlations between markets and the entire distribution (histogram of k-1 states) represents a macroeconomic general equilibrium. You could think of the Walrasian auctioneer as establishing the distribution of these boxes. They could be correlated by e.g. common factors of production or coordination by government. Let's color-code the correlated markets:

This is the picture I was describing here with regard to national income accounting identities where I said that A = G + Y + P (output A is green markets plus yellow markets plus purple markets) can be thought of as "causal" if the components like G represent correlated markets (say, the financial sector).
Now the boxes will move around inside the (macro) distribution, so while a market might be in one k-1 state at one time, it can move to another k-1 state later. The average k-1 price growth state (that sets inflation) can be relatively constant over short periods of time (but seems to generally decline). However, as long as a market stays in one particular state, the ideal price will grow at the rate (k-1) β where β is the growth rate of the common factor of production B. The observed price will fall below this value (shown in the green market below) or be closer to ideal (purple market).

In terms of the information transfer model, we can see these boxes as containing ideal gases where the ideal (purple) box is in a maximum entropy state while the green box has agent correlations (say, a panic):

I've previous said that we should try to understand sticky prices not as individual prices being rigid, but rather as the resistance of the entire distribution to change.
Now that we have this picture, let's create a dictionary matching Glasner's quote with the language of information transfer ...
General equilibrium: Each market in information equilibrium and a stable distribution of markets
Tatonnement: The process of moving toward the entropy maximum. Importantly there are two of these -- the entropy maximum represented by information equilibrium in each market (think Gary Becker's irrational agents), but also the entropy maximum in the ensemble of markets (partition function).
Equilibrium price: Information equilibrium price p
Disequilibrium price: Non-ideal information transfer price p* < p
Equilibrium price vector: The set of all equilibrium prices for each market in each k-1 state
Excess demand/supply: the demand/supply (probability) distribution in an individual market doesn't match the (probability) distribution of supply/demand
Glasner's complaint is that we don't know if tatonnement will let us reach general equilibrium and we don't know that every market is even at its equilibrium price, much less that raising a price in a market with excess demand or lowering it in a market with excess supply leads to that general equilibrium.
In the information transfer picture, this is a valid complaint. We could easily have non-ideal information transfer in each market and therefore even if the macro distribution of markets was a (stable) maximum entropy distribution, there is no guarantee that would represent a general equilibrium. The case above with 4 boxes shows such a case -- only 1 of the markets is in information equilibrium:

However we have also connected the process of moving toward equilibrium in each individual market with the same process of moving toward the macro equilibrium: both are entropy maximizing processes. And entropy maximizing process in the individual markets will match up the supply and demand distributions (i.e. achieve information equilibrium). Additionally, the macro equilibrium (the distribution of price states) becomes a necessary but not sufficient condition for the entire system (and therefore a fortiori the individual markets) to be in information equilibrium -- a step towards Glasner's macrofoundations of micro.
In a sense, we have turned the resolution of Glasner's complaint into an assumption that agents do not stay in a stable correlated state in a large fraction of markets (either independently in each market, or even correlated across markets) for extended periods of time. One way to picture it is as Keynes' animal spirits:
Even apart from the instability due to speculation, there is the instability due to the characteristic of human nature that a large proportion of our positive activities depend on spontaneous optimism rather than mathematical expectations, whether moral or hedonistic or economic. Most, probably, of our decisions to do something positive, the full consequences of which will be drawn out over many days to come, can only be taken as the result of animal spirits—a spontaneous urge to action rather than inaction, and not as the outcome of a weighted average of quantitative benefits multiplied by quantitative probabilities.
That is to say animal spirits will drive humans from a stable correlation to explore the state space, becoming uncorrelated and maximizing entropy in the process. A box of crickets released in one corner of a room will lead to a state with a near-uniform distribution of crickets.
Basically, we assume information equilibrium is a good approximation most of the time. However, we then test that assumption using data. The assumption is justified because the theory that results from it is empirically accurate (to a given level of accuracy).
It is necessary to understand, however, this assumption breaks down in recessions where as a group our desires to move to less risky assets (financial crisis) or our outlook becomes uniformly pessimistic (via interest rate signals from the Fed or forecasts).